The Jewish Independent about uscontact ussearch
Shalom Dancers Dome of the Rock Street in Israel Graffiti Jewish Community Center Kids Wailing Wall
Serving British Columbia Since 1930
homethis week's storiesarchivescommunity calendarsubscribe
 


home > this week's story

 

special online features
faq
about judaism
business & community directory
vancouver tourism tips
links

Search the Jewish Independent:


 

 

archives

Dec. 15, 2006

For free enterprise and free will

Renowned economist adopted Smith's laissez-faire approach as his standard for policy.
EUGENE KAELLIS

Milton Friedman died this year at the age of 94. He was born in Brooklyn, the son of Jewish immigrant parents from Austria-Hungary. Friedman was an outstanding student and easily made his way up the university education ladder, concentrating on economics and mathematics. Most of his academic career was spent at the University of Chicago. He was awarded the Nobel Prize in 1976.

During his lengthy and prolific lifetime, Friedman became the leader of a school of economists that advocated the return to the free enterprise system of Adam Smith, whose treatise, The Wealth of Nations (1776), is the "proof text" of believers in laissez-faire economics, with government playing as minimal a role as possible in the economy and, indeed, in everything else. Friedman, for example, opposed government-operated pensions, such as the Canada Pension Plan or Old Age Security, minimum wages, regulation of foods and drugs, compulsory and free public schooling, restrictions on banned substances, compulsory licensing of doctors, the establishment of national parks and certainly Canada's public health-care system.

He opposed government programs on the grounds that they are based on politics, rather than sound economics, they are mismanaged by huge, expensive bureaucracies; they provide undeserved rewards in the form of import duties and subsidies for groups that lobby intensively, they offer opportunities for corruption and, most of all, they are often ineffective.

While Smith was the patron saint of free enterprise economics, he was just one of a number of theorists who sprang up during a period of vast economic and political changes in Britain, the leading country of the day: Smith, Ricardo, Bentham, Malthus, Mill and, later, Darwin, Marx and Engels and a number of utopian socialists and anarcho-syndicalists. Most of them paved the way for capitalism – by providing its theory – and for civil liberties in a democratic society. Some had what we would today call humane outlooks. Others, for example, Malthus, blamed the poor for over-producing progeny and some, of course, advocated overthrowing capitalism, by force if needed, and its replacement by socialism.

Friedman, and the so-called Chicago School he helped found, sincerely felt that Smith's "invisible hand" of self-interest would ultimately sort out the economic and related social problems of society in a more consistent, more equitable, more effective and efficient manner than would government intervention. His arguments were brilliant, inventive and creative and his energy in advocating them almost inexhaustible, but part of the problem lies in "ultimately." It is a word used by some Marxists too: "ultimately," the USSR would have evolved along classical socialist-communist lines. Stalinism, it turns out, was just a 30-year aberration.

Friedman's ideas challenged Keynesianism, a policy highly influential in determining government conditioning of the economy: tax in good times, inject the accumulated capital in bad times. Friedman opposed John Maynard Keynes's theories, favoring a monetary, rather than a fiscal, policy, meaning that the government should increase the supply of money at a steady, unalterable rate. He believed that Keynesian methods were always applied too late to be effective. By the time the government became aware of a recession, it could do little to avoid its deepening. One wonders how potent this argument would be today, with enormous and almost immediate data collection and rapid processing by computers. One can even wonder if the failed planned economy of the USSR, for example, would have fared better if everything had been computerized.

Some of the major criticism directed against Friedman was that he had in mind an economy of competing businesses that would increase productivity and lower prices through competition. Friedman, of course, knew that capitalism had strayed very far from the free enterprise model of its early days, so he also advocated a ruthless application of the antitrust laws and strict controls of the equities market. However, if big business is to be believed, the economy of scale, i.e., bringing prices down by the mass production of commodities for a national and international market, is dependent on some form of monopoly. Hardly a week goes by without news of a merger or acquisition. Advocating a return to small businesses seems somewhat reminiscent of the backyard steel furnaces of Mao's cultural revolution. Try making a bus or truck that way. Corporations claim that the growth of monopolies, by rationalizing production and through economies of scale, have improved standards of living.

Friedman realized, of course, that some people, for a variety of reasons, cannot support themselves. He therefore became an early advocate of the "negative income tax," a sort of guaranteed annual income. With Friedman's encyclopedic knowledge of economics, he must have known that something similar was tried from 1795 to 1834 in Berkshire, England.

It was a desperate measure by a local government faced with unprecedented unemployment and misery that resulted from the capitalization of a formerly feudal agriculture and the inability of new industries to provide adequate jobs. Employers in the Speenhamland Plan, as it was known, simply lowered subsistence wages, letting the government make up the difference. Canada tried a brief experiment, allegedly successful, with a Guaranteed Annual Income in Dauphin, Man., some years ago, but no political party has so far advocated it.

In line with his laissez-faire economic policy, Friedman was also an extreme civil libertarian. Many North Americans would today join him in opposing security measures to counter terrorism. It may comfort them to remember that democracies are resilient. In the United States, despite the Alien and Sedition Act to protect the country from subversion after the French Revolution, the suspension of habeas corpus during the Civil War, the Palmer Raids and Red Scare after the Bolshevik Revolution, the McCarran Act, McCarthyism, the House Un-American Activities Committee and now the Patriot Act, America has always returned to its basic system of freedom after the danger subsided.

Friedman would likely not have objected to being called an ideologue, although that word has acquired a pejorative sense. It's interesting, therefore, to review historically what happened to the plans of other ideologues. After the Bolshevik seizure of power and the consequent disruption of industry and agriculture, both of which had made substantial progress under the czar, Lenin devised the New Economic Plan, a form of limited capitalism needed to undo the damage and to continue the accumulation of primary capital, vital to economic growth.

And now, "communist" China has a rapidly growing capitalist system. Mao's Cultural Revolution, the last gasp of utopian ideology, advocated the backyard production of steel. Perhaps the Chinese government is just waiting for further industrial development before it "returns" to its socialist dream. Could that be accomplished without another revolution?

Friedman was a strong advocate for free trade. He certainly took issue with aspects of NAFTA, but on the whole supported it, as a lesser of evils. He also supported the outsourcing of jobs to Asia and Latin America. We will have to wait a few decades to find out if such measures actually improve the lives of people here and abroad.

Democracy means individual freedom and economic freedom, both within bounds designed to protect individual rights, uphold group rights, protect enterprise as well as the working and consuming public. It is, in other words, a constantly adjusting balance between contending interests and forces.

Regardless of whether one agrees or disagrees with Friedman, it must be conceded that he made important, well-reasoned contributions to determining where the balance point should be.

Eugene Kaellis
is a retired academic living in New Westminster.

^TOP